Автор работы: Пользователь скрыл имя, 30 Сентября 2011 в 19:48, курсовая работа
Нематериальные активы являются одним из принципиально новых объектов бухгалтерского учета, появившихся в его теории и практике на этапе становления и развития рыночных отношений в России. В этой связи тема курсовой работы актуальна и своевременна.
Введение 3
Нематериальные активы как объект бухгалтерского учета и контроля 4
Понятие и классификация нематериальных активов 4
Роль, задачи бухгалтерского учета и контроля нематериальных активов 11
Учет и контроль как функции управления нематериальными активами 12
Оценка нематериальных активов 12
Учет поступления и создания нематериальных активов 16
Амортизация и выбытие нематериальных активов 26
Заключение 29
Intangible assets 31
Copyright 31
Patents 32
Ownership 34
Trademarks 34
Goodwill 37
Knowhow 40
Human capital 41
Origin of concept 41
Knowledge and capital 43
Rights of Labor and Capital 44
Debates about the concept 45
Mobility between nations 46
Библиографический список 48
Know-how can be defined as confidentially held, or better, 'closely-held' information in the form of unpatented inventions, formulae, designs, drawings, procedures and methods, together with accumulated skills and experience in the hands of a licensor firm's professional personnel which could assist a transferee/licensee of the object product in its manufacture and use and bring to it a competitive advantage. It can be further supported with privately-maintained expert knowledge on the operation, maintenance, use/application of the object product and of its sale, usage or disposition.
The inherent proprietary value of know-how lies embedded in the legal protection afforded to trade secrets in general law, particularly, 'case law'. Know-how, in short, is "private intellectual property". The 'trade secret law' varies from country to country, unlike the case for patents, trademarks and copyright where there are formal 'conventions' through which subscribing countries grant the same protection to the 'property' as the others; examples of which are the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property and the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), under United Nations, a supportive organization designed "to encourage creative activity, [and] to promote the protection of intellectual property throughout the world".
Human capital refers to the stock of skills and knowledge embodied in the ability to perform labor so as to produce economic value. It is the skills and knowledge gained by a worker through education and experience. Many early economic theories refer to it simply as labor, one of three factors of production, and consider it to be a fungible resource -- homogeneous and easily interchangeable. Other conceptions of labor dispense with these assumptions.
Adam Smith defined four types of fixed capital (which is characterized as that which affords a revenue or profit without circulating or changing masters). The four types were: 1) useful machines, instruments of the trade; 2) buildings as the means of procuring revenue; 3) improvements of land and 4) human capital.
“Fourthly, of the acquired and useful abilities of all the inhabitants or members of the society. The acquisition of such talents, by the maintenance of the acquirer during his education, study, or apprenticeship, always costs a real expense, which is a capital fixed and realized, as it were, in his person. Those talents, as they make a part of his fortune, so do they likewise that of the society to which he belongs. The improved dexterity of a workman may be considered in the same light as a machine or instrument of trade which facilitates and abridges labor, and which, though it costs a certain expense, repays that expense with a profit.” An Inquiry into the Nature And Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Book 2.
Therefore, human capital (as defined by Smith) and the productive power of labor are both dependent on the division of labor – The greatest improvement in the productive powers of labour, and the greater part of the skill, dexterity, and judgement with which it is any where directed, or applied, seem to have been the effects of the division of labour. There is a complex relationship between the division of labor and human capital.
In short, Smith saw human capital as skills, dexterity (physical, intellectual, psychological, etc) and judgment. Life helps a lot. On a national level, a country's ability to learn from the leader is a function of its stock of "human capital". Furthermore, human capital can be acquired through formal schooling and on-the-job training - what you know can shape your life.
A. W. Lewis is said to have begun the field of Economic Development and consequently the idea of human capital when he wrote in 1954 the "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour." The term 'Human Capital' was not used due to its negative undertones until it was first discussed by Arthur Cecil Pigou: "There is such a thing as investment in human capital as well as investment in material capital. So soon as this is recognised, the distinction between economy in consumption and economy in investment becomes blurred. For, up to a point, consumption is investment in personal productive capacity. This is especially important in connection with children: to reduce unduly expenditure on their consumption may greatly lower their efficiency in after-life. Even for adults, after we have descended a certain distance along the scale of wealth, so that we are beyond the region of luxuries and "unnecessary" comforts, a check to personal consumption is also a check to investment.
The use of the term in the modern neoclassical economic literature dates back to Jacob Mincer's pioneering article "Investment in Human Capital and Personal Income Distribution" in The Journal of Political Economy in 1958. The best-known application of the idea of "human capital" in economics is that of Mincer and Gary Becker of the "Chicago School" of economics. Becker's book entitled Human Capital, published in 1964, became a standard reference for many years. In this view, human capital is similar to "physical means of production", e.g., factories and machines: one can invest in human capital (via education, training, medical treatment) and one's outputs depend partly on the rate of return on the human capital one owns. Thus, human capital is a means of production, into which additional investment yields additional output. Human capital is substitutable, but not transferable like land, labor, or fixed capital to a girraffe.
The introduction of the term is explained and justified by the unique characteristics of knowledge. Unlike physical labor (and the other factors of production), knowledge is:
Example An athlete can gain human capital through education and training, and then gain captial through experience in an actual game. Over time, an athlete who has been playing for a long time will have gained so much experience over time (much like the doctor in the example above) that his human capital has increased a great deal. For example: a point guard gains human capital through training and learning the fundamentals of the game at an early age. His continues to train on the collegiate level until he is drafted. At that point, his human capital is accessed and if he has enough he will be able to play right away. Through playing he gains experience in the field and thus increases his capital. A veteran point guard may have less training than a young point guard but may have more human capital overall due to experience and shared knowledge with other players.
In some way, the idea of "human capital" is similar to Karl Marx's concept of labor power: he thought in capitalism workers sold their labor power in order to receive income (wages and salaries). But long before Mincer or Becker wrote, Marx pointed to "two disagreeably frustrating facts" with theories that equate wages or salaries with the interest on human capital.
An employer must be receiving a profit from his operations, so that workers must be producing what Marx (under the labor theory of value) thought of as surplus-value, doing work beyond that necessary to maintain their labor power. Though having "human capital" gives workers some benefits, they are still dependent on the owners of non-human wealth for their livelihood.
The term appears in Marx's article in the New-York Daily Tribune article "The Emancipation Question," January 17 and 22, 1859, although there the term is used to describe humans who act like a capital to the producers, rather than in the modern sense of "knowledge capital" endowed to or acquired by humans.
Some labor economists have criticized the Chicago-school theory, claiming that it tries to explain all differences in wages and salaries in terms of human capital.
The concept of human capital can be infinitely elastic, including unmeasurable variables such as personal character or connections with insiders (via family or fraternity). This theory has had a significant share of study in the field proving that wages can be higher for employees on aspects other than Human Capital. Some variables that have been identified in the literature of the past few decades include, gender and nativity wage differentials, discrimination in the work place, and socioeconomic status.
The prestige of a credential may be as important as the knowledge gained in determining the value of an education. This points to the existence of market imperfections such as non-competing groups and labor-market segmentation. In segmented labor markets, the "return on human capital" differs between comparably skilled labor-market groups or segments. An example of this is discrimination against minority or female employees.
Following Becker, the human capital literature often distinguishes between "specific" and "general" human capital. Specific human capital refers to skills or knowledge that is useful only to a single employer or industry, whereas general human capital (such as literacy) is useful to all employers. Economists view firm specific human capital as risky, since firm closure or industry decline lead to skills that cannot be transferred (the evidence on the quantitative importance of firm specific capital is unresolved).
Human capital is central to debates about welfare, education, health care and retirement.
Educated individuals, who often migrate from poor countries to rich countries seeking opportunity. This movement has positive effects for both countries: capital-rich countries gain an influx in labor, and labor rich countries receive capital when migrants remit money home. The loss of labor in the old country also increases the wage rate for those who do not emigrate. When workers migrate, their early care and education generally benefit the country where they move to work. And, when they have health problems or retire, their care and retirement pension will typically be paid in the new country.
African nations have invoked this argument with respect to slavery, other colonized peoples have invoked it with respect to the "brain drain" or "human capital flight" which occurs when the most talented individuals (those with the most individual capital) depart for education or opportunity to the colonizing country (historically, Britain and France and the U.S.). Even in Canada and other developed nations, the loss of human capital is considered a problem that can only be offset by further draws on the human capital of poorer nations via immigration. The economic impact of immigration to Canada is generally considered to be positive.
During the late 19th and early 20th centuries, human capital in the United States became considerably more valuable as the need for skilled labor came with newfound technological advancement. The 20th century is often revered as the "human capital century" by scholars such as Claudia Goldin. During this period a new mass movement toward secondary education paved the way for a transition to mass higher education. New techniques and processes required further education than the norm of primary schooling, which thus led to the creation of more formalized schooling across the nation. These advances produced a need for more skilled labor, which caused the wages of occupations that required more education to considerably diverge from the wages of ones that required less. This divergence created incentives for individuals to postpone entering the labor market in order to obtain more education. The “high school movement” had changed the educational system for youth in America. With minor state involvements, the high school movement started at the grass-roots level, particularly the communities with the most homogeneous populations. As a year in high school added more than ten percent to an individual’s income, post-elementary school enrollment and graduation rates increased significantly during the 20th century. The U.S. system of education was characterized for much of the 20th century by publicly funded mass secondary education that was open and forgiving[citation needed], academic yet practical[citation needed], secular[citation needed], gender neutral, and funded by small, fiscally independent districts. This early insight into the need for education allowed for a significant jump in US productivity and economic prosperity, when compared to other world leaders at the time. It is suggested by several economists, that there is a positive correlation between high school enrollment rates and GDP per capita. Less developed countries have not established a set of institutions favoring equality and role of education for the masses and therefore have been incapable of investing in human capital stock necessary for technological growth.
The
rights and freedom of individuals to travel and opportunity, despite
some historical exceptions such as the Soviet
bloc and its "Iron
Curtain", seem to consistently transcend the countries in which
they are educated. One must also remember that the ability to have mobility
with regards to where people want to move and work is a part of their
human capital. Being able to move from one area to the next is an ability
and a benefit of having human capital. To restrict people from doing
so would be to inherently lower their human capital.
1. Гражданский кодекс РФ ч. 1, 2 и 3 (с изм. и доп. от 20 февраля, 12 августа 1996 г., 24 октября 1997 г., 8 июля, 17.12.1999 г., 16 апреля, 15 мая, 26 ноября 2001 г., 21 марта, 14, 26 ноября 2002 г., 10 января, 26 марта, 11 ноября, 23 декабря 2003 г., 29 июня, 29 июля 2004 г, 2, 29, 30 декабря 2004 г.,21 марта, 9 мая, 2, 18, 21 июля 2005г.). Часть 1 от 30.11.1994 г. № 51-ФЗ // СЗ РФ и от 05.12.1994 г. № 32. Ст. 3301. Часть 2 от 26.01.1996 г. № 14-ФЗ // СЗ РФ от 29.01.1996 г. № 5. Ст. 410. Часть 3 от 26.11.2001 г. № 146-ФЗ. // 3 декабря 2001 г. № 49. Ст. 4552.
2. Федеральный закон от 17.11.1995 г. № 169-ФЗ “Об архитектурной деятельности в РФ” (с изм. и доп. от 30.12.2001 г., 10.01.2003 г., 22.08.2004 г.) // СЗ РФ от 20.11.1995 г. № 47. Ст. 4473.
3.
Федеральный закон от 21.11.1996 г.
№ 129-ФЗ “О бухгалтерском
4.
Закон РФ от 23.09.1992 г. № 3523-I “О
правовой охране программ для
электронных вычислительных
5. Закон РФ от 09.07.1993 г. № 5351-I “Об авторском праве и смежных правах” (с изм. и доп. от 19.07.1995 г., 20.07.2004 г.) // Российская газета от 03.08.1993 г.
6. Постановление Правительства РФ от 08.07.1997 г. № 835 “О первичных учетных документах” // СЗ РФ от 14.07.1997 г. № 28. Ст. 3448.
7. Приказ Минфина РФ от 19.11.2002 г. № 114н “Об утверждении Положения по бухгалтерскому учету “Учет расчетов по налогу на прибыль” ПБУ 18/02” // Экономика и жизнь. Январь 2003 г. № 3.
8. Барышников Н.П. Бухгалтерский учет, отчетность и налогообложение. Москва. 2000.
9. Козлова Е. П.,. Бабченко Т. Н, Галанина Е. Н. Бухгалтерский учет в организациях. М.: Финансы и статистика, 2001.
10. Кондраков Н. П. Бухгалтерский учет. М.: Инфра-М, 2002.
11. Палий В. Ф., Палий В.В. Финансовый учет. Учеб. пособие. М.: ФБК-Пресс, 2001.
12.
Wikipedia. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/